Hannah Montana fan club members to sue the fan club. Hopefully the judge is a Bayesian

This is a re-post. For some reason pieces of the original did not upload and I was too tired to even check. This morning I added the regression stuff.

While I’m in the mood to update old stories: here’s the latest one about Hannah Montana

Thousands of “Hannah Montana” fans who couldn’t get concert tickets could potentially join a lawsuit against the teen performer’s fan club over memberships they claim were supposed to give them priority for seats.

The lawsuit was filed on behalf of a New Jersey woman and anyone else who joined the Miley Cyrus Fan Club based on its promise that joining would make it easier to get concert tickets from the teen star’s Web site.

“They deceptively lured thousands of individuals into purchasing memberships into the Miley Cyrus Fan Club,” plaintiffs’ attorney Rob Peirce said. His Pittsburgh firm and a Memphis firm filed the suit Tuesday in U.S. District Court in Nashville.

The fan club costs $29.95 a year to join, according to the lawsuit, which alleges that the defendants should have known that the site’s membership vastly exceeded the number of tickets.

What an interesting club they have. At least they like to do things together? It seems these are people who either (a) honestly did purchase membership with this club in order to get preferential access to concert tickets, or (b) are now saying they did because taking responsibility for things just not working out is so unfashionable, these days. Who knows.

I guess it’s just a lawsuit, like any other. I’ve looked around: I don’t see any mention of the actual number of members of this fan club (perhaps it’s made known once you are a member and log in?). If this number was known then, yes, I would say it should be clear to members that more people will want tickets than will get them. “Thousands” are in on this lawsuit, so I figure it ought to be a lot.

The solution is simple: compare the two sets of people, members and non-members. There must be some measure of the non-member fans of the girl – perhaps people who tried and failed to get tickets via the members’ site? If, conditional upon being a member, one was in fact more likely to have gotten tickets than the general public, there is no lawsuit. If the opposite is found (i.e. if there appears to have been no advantage), there there is a lawsuit.

Bayes’ Theory

Enter Bayes’ theory: suppose we want/need the probability of getting tickets conditional upon being a Miley Cyrus Fan Club member. We don’t have that, per se. What we do have is the probability of being a Fan Club member conditional upon (a) getting tickets, and (b) not getting tickets. With this, we can work.

First, define A1 = Getting Tickets, A2 = Not Getting Tickets, B1 = Fan Club Member and, finally, B2 = Not A Fan Club Member.

So, the probability we need is

Pr (A_{1}|B_{1})=\frac{\Pr \left( A_{1}\cap B_{1}\right) }{\Pr (B_{1})}

to compare to

Pr (A_{1}|B_{2})=\frac{\Pr \left( A_{1}\cap B_{2}\right) }{\Pr (B_{2})}

What we observe (or can observe) are Pr (B_{1}|A_{1}), Pr (B_{2}|A_{1}), Pr (B_{1}|A_{2}) and Pr (B_{2}|A_{2}), where (for example)

Pr (B_{1}|A_{1})=\frac{\Pr \left( A_{1}\cap B_{1}\right) }{\Pr (A_{1})}

and so forth. Now, the probability

Pr (B_{1}|A_{1})=\frac{\Pr \left( A_{1}\cap B_{1}\right) }{\Pr (A_{1})}

for example, gives us

Pr \left( A_{1}\cap B_{1}\right) =\Pr (B_{1}|A_{1})\times \Pr (A_{1})

Repeating that, we see that the probability that we need is given by

Pr (A_{1}|B_{1})=\frac{\Pr \left( A_{1}\cap B_{1}\right) }{\Pr \left( A_{1}\cap B_{1}\right) +\Pr \left( A_{2}\cap B_{1}\right) }

This is because our outcomes are clearly defined: they are mutually exclusive, and they are exhaustive – i.e.

Pr (B_{1})=\Pr \left( A_{1}\cap B_{1}\right) +\Pr \left( A_{2}\cap B_{1}\right)

Same for B2. Thus will we get the two numbers that need to answer the questions: (1) what was the probability of getting tickets conditional upon being a Miley Cyrus Fan Club member; and (2) was it greater than the probability of securing tickets conditional upon not being a fan club member? I should point out here that the tricky part of this is going to be finding A2 and Pr(A2 ). Less so, perhaps for members of the Miley Cyrus Fan Club than for the general population. The value of that information will make a very big difference to our conditional probabilities: what if, for example, they are different numbers, but very similar numbers? How different do they have to be? Enter the \chi ^{2} (pronounced ky, to rhyme with sky) test for independence.

Chi-squared

The \chi ^{2} test for independence will test for us the null hypothesis (the default hypothesis) that Pr (A_{1}|B_{1}) = Pr (A_{1}|B_{2}), versus the alternative that Pr (A_{1}|B_{1}) \neq Pr (A_{1}|B_{2}). For this we need all four possible joint observed cells:

Freq_Table1

If the two probabilities are in fact equal, then we would expect to see (for example):

Frq_Table3

Then we calculate our test statistic:

\chi ^{2}=\dfrac{\left[ a-\dfrac{d(a+b)}{(d+c)}\right] ^{2}}{\dfrac{d(a+b)}{%  (d+c)}}+\dfrac{\left[ b-\dfrac{c(a+b)}{(d+c)}\right] ^{2}}{\dfrac{c(a+b)}{%  (d+c)}}

(This equation refuses to convert. I’ll fix it later). Here you go (anyone want to explain why the equation beats the WordPress renderer?):

test stat

I.e. the sum of the squared values of the (observed – expected) cells for each of the two outcomes. This could also be done the other way around, or using the Tickets columns, rather than the Membership rows. With n – 1 = 1 degree of freedom, we just need that statistic to be greater than 3.84:

chi_squared table

to reject our null hypothesis and conclude that the distribution of ticket-getting was in fact different for Miley Cyrus Fan Club members than for non-members. If the members had a higher conditional probability of securing tickets then, again, there is no case. If they are not statistically significantly different, they’ve been ripped-off. Again, whether they should have known this beforehand is a matter for a jury: we just do the numbers.

Done? Not even close. What if there was more to it than that?

Regression

Regression analysis: regression analysis will offer two distinct advantages in this instance; one for the prosecution, and definitely if the defence has demonstrated, above, than Miley Cyrus Fan Club members did in fact get a better deal on tickets than non-members, and one for the defence, for the same reason:

  1. Regression analysis will be able to quantify the degree to which being a member of the fan club increased the probability of securing a ticket to the show(s).
  2. Regression analysis will be able to identify the statistical significance of the relationship between fan club membership and ticket-securing, controlling for other factors.

Our regression model appears thus:

Pr(\text{Securing Tickets}) = \beta _{0}+\beta _{1}\left( \text{Membership}\right) +\varepsilon

Keeping it simple Ordinary Least Squared. That is part (1): this model will positively identify whether being a member of the fan club (a dummy variable: 0 = not a member; 1 = member) affects the probability of securing tickets. For purposes of compensation, it will also quantify the degree to which that probability increased (if it increased at all).

However. What if there was some other difference? We know, for example, that scalpers landed on these tickets like (insert joke here – who don’t you like?). Suppose Miley Cyrus Fan Club members differed in some specific other respect? Perhaps they just didn’t log on as quickly? Do they have a slower connection? Was a child doing it with their parents credit card (the assumption being that they were slower to manoeuvre the system)? On to multiple regression! Controlling for these factors, our model becomes:

Pr(\text{Securing Tickets}) = \beta _{0}+\beta _{1}\left( \text{Membership}\right) +\beta _{2}\left( \text{Timeliness}\right) +\beta _{3}\left( \text{Internet Speed}\right) +\beta _{4}\left( \text{Age of Purchaser}\right) +\varepsilon

The more statistically significant explanatory variables we introduce into our model, the less statistically significant (and, probably, economically significant) beta _{1} will become, and the weaker will become the class action lawsuit against the Hannah Montana people.

Seems like a waste of perfectly good econometrics/statistics, one might think. The suit will probably contain every fan club member who did not get a ticket, though, asking for triple damages plus legal fees. I reckon it’s worth the effort for the companies being sued.

I keep telling my students that econometrics can do everything…

Advertisements

10 comments so far

  1. peter sivey on

    What if membership is endogenous? Fans who become members might be more likely to ‘try harder’ to get the tickets. They will make sure they know the exact date tickets are on sale, refresh their web browser more times trying to get to the tickets page. Some of these things might be in your control variables, but maybe more are unobserved, biasing beta1 upwards. 🙂

    Economists *pretend* econometrics can solve anything!

    Pete

  2. zooeygoethe on

    I said assuming OLS – I’m assuming iid Normal errors. And my multiple regression model is incomplete, almost certainly. Don’t be a trouble-maker.

    Everyone else, Pete (former office-mate, so I can call him names freely, the jerk) is referring to selection bias (probably correctly). If people are electing to become fan club members for the purpose of getting tickets, there is the distinct possibility that they are going to make more of an effort.

    There is, however, also the possibility that being members generates ticket-securing-complacancy: perhaps they made less effort.

    Either way, the OLS assusmption that the error terms are independent and identicically distributed breaks down: the errors make be structural, meaning correlated with the explanatory variables.

    E.g., suppose systematically more variance is observed in one membership category than the other; or, as Pete said, some third variable is explaining both one’s success at getting a ticket and one’s membership in the fan club – call it Initiative. This is a very hard thing to go out and measure.

    I never defended Economists. I would remind Pete, though, that simple Economics has already explained both how this problem arose, and why, and what might easily have been done to prevent it, or correct it after the fact. The problem here wasn’t economics, it was ‘hurricane people’ and class-action litigation firms …

    Plus, 3 years ago, he was the one giving me stick for not calling myself an Economist. Pete: do give my regards to those roosting chickens you’ve got coming home.

  3. […] Hannah Montana fan club members to sue the fan club. Hopefully the … […]

  4. nadya on

    je t aime peut tu venir a roubaix cun jour

  5. freneticfangirl on

    okay ilove u hannah montana lol hahahahahahahahahahaha!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!.

  6. hannaah montan on

    ilove 4our conc tsi
    one im to see annweait to see another

    one,uour newest like
    watch pretttysmie ilike to
    ver4 smat
    eddie talbot
    6507hid
    832o1pocatello

  7. malvika on

    i am a greatest fan of hannah montana.
    i love all her songs.

    best of both worlds is my favorite song.

    I LOVE YOU HANNAH MONTANA AND I AM A GREAT FAN OF HER.

  8. anna on

    lalalalalalalalalalallalalalala………………

    i will always be singing your best of both worlds.

    I LLLLLLLLLLLLLLLLLLLLLLLOVE MILEY .

  9. charlene on

    hi

  10. Anonymous on

    hiiiiiiiii hannah


Leave a Reply

Fill in your details below or click an icon to log in:

WordPress.com Logo

You are commenting using your WordPress.com account. Log Out / Change )

Twitter picture

You are commenting using your Twitter account. Log Out / Change )

Facebook photo

You are commenting using your Facebook account. Log Out / Change )

Google+ photo

You are commenting using your Google+ account. Log Out / Change )

Connecting to %s

%d bloggers like this: